Class before Trumponomics, part 3

Posted: 2 December 2016 in Uncategorized
Tags: , , , , , , , , , , , ,
alec

Alec Monopoly, “Flying Monopoly” (2015)

In the second installment of this series on “class before Trumponomics,” I argued that, in recent decades, while American workers have created enormous wealth, most of the increase in that wealth has been captured by their employers and a tiny group at the top—as workers have been forced to compete with one another for new kinds of jobs, with fewer protections, at lower wages, and with less security than they once expected. And the period of recovery from the Second Great Depression has done nothing to change that fundamental dynamic.

In this post, I want to focus on a more detailed analysis of the other side of the class relationship—capital.

fire

It should come as no surprise that one of the major changes in U.S. capital over the past few decades is the growing importance of financial activities. Since 1980, FIRE (finance, insurance, and real estate) has almost doubled, expanding from roughly 12 percent of the gross output of private industries to over 20 percent.

finance

And the rise in the share of corporate profits from financial activities was even more spectacular—from 10.8 percent in 1984 to a whopping 37.4 percent in 2002—and then falling during the crash, but still at a historically high 26.6 percent in 2015.

By any measure, U.S. capital became increasingly oriented toward finance beginning in the early 1980s—as traditional banks (deposit-gathering commercial banks), non-bank financial entities (especially shadow banking, such as investment banks, hedge funds, insurers and other non-bank financial institutions), and even the financial arm of industrial corporations (such as the General Motors Acceptance Corporation, now Ally Financial) absorbed and then profited by creating new claims on the surplus.

This process of “financialization” was the flip side of the decreasing labor share in the U.S. economy: On one hand, stagnant wages meant both an increasing surplus, which could be recycled via the financial sector, and a growing market for loans, as workers sought to maintain their customary level of consumption via increasing indebtedness. On the other hand, the production of commodities (both goods and services) became less important than capturing a portion of the surplus from around the world, and utilizing it via issuing loans and selling derivatives to receive even more.

international

Not only did finance become increasingly internationalized, so did the U.S. economy as a whole. As a result of employers’ decisions to outsource the production of commodities that had previously been manufactured in the United States and to find external markets for the sale of other commodities (especially services), and with the assistance of the lowering of tariffs and the signing of new trade agreements, the U.S. economy was increasingly opened up from the early-1970s onward. One indicator of this globalization is the increase in the weight of international trade (the sum of exports and imports) in relation to U.S. GDP—more than tripling between 1970 (9.33 percent) to 2014 (29.1 percent).

bank-concentration

The third major change in U.S. capital in recent decades is a rise in the degree of corporate concentration and centralization—to such an extent even the President’s Council of Economic Advisers (pdf) has taken notice. A wave of mergers and acquisitions has made firms larger and has increased the degree of market concentration within a broad range of industries. In finance, for example, the market share of the five largest banks (measured in terms of their assets as a share of total commercial banking assets) more than doubled between 1996 and 2014—rising from 23.2 percent to 47.9 percent.

airlines

The U.S. airline industry also experienced considerable merger and acquisition activity, especially following deregulation in 1978. The figure above (from a report by the U.S. Government Accountability Office [pdf]) provides a timeline of mergers and acquisitions for the four largest surviving domestic airlines—American, Delta, Southwest, and United—based on the number of passengers served. These four airlines accounted for approximately 85 percent of total passenger traffic in the United States in 2013.

profits-interest

Another piece of evidence that concentration and centralization have increased within the U.S. economy is (following Jason Furmanthe growing gap between corporate profits and interest-rates. The fact that corporate profits (as a share of national income, the top line in the chart above) have risen while interest-rates (the nominal constant-maturity 1-year rate estimated by the Federal Reserve, less inflation defined by the Consumer Price Index, the bottom line in the chart above) indicates that the portion of profits created by oligopoly rents has grown in recent decades.*

fire-mfg

Together, the three main tendencies I have highlighted—financialization, internationalization, and corporate rents—indicate a fundamental change in U.S. capital since the 1980s, which has continued during the current recovery. One of the effects of those changes is a decline in the importance of manufacturing, especially in relation to FIRE, as can be seen in the chart above. Manufacturing (as measured by value added as a percentage of GDP) has declined from 22.9 percent (in 1970) to 12 percent (in 2015), while FIRE moved in the opposite direction—from 14.2 percent to 20.3 percent. Quantitatively, the two sectors have traded places, which qualitatively signifies a change in how U.S. capital manages to capture the surplus. While it still appropriates surplus from its own workers (although now more in the production and export of services than in manufacturing), it now captures the surplus, from workers inside and outside the United States, via financial activities. On top of that, the largest firms are capturing additional portions of the surplus from other, smaller corporations via oligopoly rents.

13205

source

What we’ve witnessed then is a fundamental transformation of U.S. capital and thus the U.S. economy, which begins to explain a whole host of recent trends—from the decrease in rates of economic growth (since capital is engaged less in investment than in other activities, such as stock buybacks, hoarding profits in the form of cash, and mergers and acquisitions) to the rise in corporate executive pay in relation to average worker pay (which has ballooned, from 29.9 in 1978 to 275.6 in 2015).

What is clear is that the decisions of U.S. capital as it changed over the course of recent decades created the conditions for the crash of 2007-08 and the unevenness of the subsequent recovery, which culminated in the victory of Donald Trump in November 2016.

 

*Another way to get at these oligopoly rents is to distinguish between the capital share and the profit share. According to Simcha Barkai (pdf), the decline in the labor share over the last 30 years was not offset by an increase in the capital share, which actually declined. But it was accompanied by an increase in the profit share, due to a rise in mark-ups.

Comments
  1. Bruce says:

    A friendly amendment, I hope, via a long argument. Your first graph shows that, as you say:

    “Since 1980, FIRE (finance, insurance, and real estate) has almost doubled, expanding from roughly 12 percent of the gross output of private industries to over 20 percent.”

    Thinking in Marxian terms, this actually understates the secular impact of FIRE. The measure of gross output here, the standard measure of GDP, is (increasingly) flawed by the absence of the concepts of “surplus” and of “unproductive” activities in the accounting conventions used.

    Marxian analysis, as I see it, views FIRE activities in general as unproductive, remunerated out of the social surplus (labor, value, product) but not in general *creating* either value or surplus. FIRE revenues, in this accounting, represent a subtraction from the surplus available for other (private or social) purposes without any corresponding addition to the social value-product. So in blunt terms, FIRE incomes result from a transfer of value, not from the creation of value.

    But the conventions of GDP accounting follow the neoclassical logic by which banking and other FIRE services are counted via an “imputation for implicitly-priced intermediation services,” creating a hypothetical quantity to represent the imagined output whose production gave rise to the income received. Apparently, because “financial services” are deemed useful by those who pay for them, those services must be treated as generators in their own right of value and output (even though there is nothing there that can actually be measured as output at all).

    (A Marxian surplus approach that recognizes unproductive activity would argue instead that not all useful services represent productive additions to social net output—risk management and liquidity provision, for example, may be useful to their consumers without being “productive” in the materialist sense—and not all costs need be classed as costs of production: FIRE does entail a “cost” for the rest of the economy, but it is a transfer-based cost rather than a production cost. From this surplus perspective, “we” don’t grow richer by transferring purchasing power.)

    In contrast, though, the standard (neoclassical) approach embedded in GDP accounting means, in concrete terms, that profits in FIRE must be treated as a reflection of rising real output generated by FIRE activities, requiring a numerical “imputation” of greater GDP. And, worse, that *rising* profits in FIRE then go hand in hand with *rising* levels of imputed “output” and hence enhanced “productivity.” So the output share of FIRE in your first graph and the profit share of FIRE in your second graph are even more closely related than you directly state. Small wonder, then, that the renewed “growth” of GDP so celebrated as the basis for the “recovery” from 2008 has felt so hollow to so many, given that a rising portion of the measured growth of aggregate real income and productivity is an illusion created by imputation, an imaginary consequence of class-driven shifts in income from wages to (especially financial) profits and the measurement conventions that transform this form of surplus appropriation and control into imputed output. The frustration that many voters apparently had with the cheery optimism of number-crunching mainstream economists and politicians (“America is already great”) has, in this Marxian view, a solid foundation, even if the causes of that frustration (including the secular trends in capitalism that you focus on in this post) remain opaque to most.

    BTW, the imputation problem is only likely to get worse: steps towards further imaginary imputations are likely, as internationally accepted accounting standards continue to ove towards a fuller application of the neoclassical conception of the “user-cost of capital,” so that interest and even capital gains may well be soon regarded as making “productive” contributions to output!

    I hope this is, in fact, a friendly amendment.

    Anyone interested in the argument here should see my article in Rethinking Marxism on this and related issues– unfortunately available only to subscribers: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/08935696.2014.917842

  2. David F. Ruccio says:

    You’re absolutely right, Bruce. The point you make is what I implied when I used the language of “capturing the surplus” from around the world. That’s how finance (at least most of finance, except the production of service commodities) gets it “value” and “profits”—through transfers from elsewhere in the national and global economy, where value and surplus are in fact created. And, yes, a value has to be imputed to finance in GDP accounting (not unlike what happens with government expenditures).

  3. […] Publicamos en esta entrada la traducción de la tercera parte del artículo de David Ruccio acerca de la evolución de la lucha de clases en EE UU durante las últimas décadas, hasta la elección de Donald Trump. El artículo original se puede encontrar en el blog de su autor. […]

  4. […] Las clases antes de la trumponomía, parte III | Rotekeil on Class before Trumponomics, part 3 […]

  5. […] installments of the first part of this series, “Class Before Trumponomics” (here, here, and here), over the course of recent decades and continuing through the crash and recovery, the class nature […]

  6. […] parts: here, here, here, here, here, here, and here), and Trumponomics (in four parts: here, here, here, and […]

  7. […] I made in my piece on “Class and Trumponomics” (serialized on this blog—here, here, here, and here—and recently published as a single article in the Real-World Economics Review [pdf]) is […]

  8. […] arguments I made in my piece on “Class and Trumponomics” (serialized on this blog—here, here, here, and here—and recently published as a single article in the Real-World Economics Review [pdf]) is […]

Leave a comment